When it comes to the US
Constitution, contrary to the famous Steve Jobs quotation, “Stay hungry, stay
foolish” it seems that America is resigned to a generally broad interpretation
of the document. We are foolish, but not in the way Jobs was suggesting—we are
foolishly uncritical of the way the Constitution has been interpreted and
applied to law. In America’s Constitution
Akhil Reed Amar brings to light just how narrow some of the current interpretations
of the Constitution are and how a broader interpretation could be beneficial to
the US both within a foreign and domestic context.
It seems intuitively wise, when
attempting to apply a document that is 226 years old to law and government in a
modern world, to “tread lightly” but that light step should not be at the cost
of thoughtful consideration of the benefits of seemingly unconventional
interpretations. When in comes to the US Constitution, parts of Section 8 and
the spirit behind which some of the economic regulations were set forth deserve
to be given a second look. Amar first points out the “Commerce Clause”: “power
to regulate Commerce with foreign Nations, and among the several Sates, and
with the Indian Tribes”. Amar writes, “modern lawyers and judges typically
refer to these words as the ‘commerce clause’ and today’s Supreme Court has
moved toward reading the paragraph as applicable only to economic interactions”
(107). Amar also includes a note that cites several articles discussing the
scope of the commerce clause but concludes that “none of these interpretations
comes to grips with the basic inadequacy of a purely economic reading of
‘commerce’” (542) Not surprisingly, Amar is correct. Which should cause one to
question if whether or not the current interpretation of Section 8 is too
narrow, and if this narrow interpretation is being set forth because a sense of
fear or an unwillingness to exert resources or energy. As Amar states, “a broader reading of
‘Commerce’ in this clause would seem to make better sense of the framers’
general goals by enabling Congress to regulate all interactions (and altercations) with foreign nations and Indian
tribes—interactions that, if improperly handled by a single state acting on its
own might lead to needless wars or otherwise compromise the interests of sister
states.” (107) In a modern context, some parts of this broad interpretation
would not make sense. For example, California, by itself probably would not be
able to start a conflict with a foreign state that would reach the level of war
unchecked. However, the idea that this clause, under a broader
interpretation, gives Congress the power
to regulate all interactions and altercations with foreign nations is
strikingly relevant. For example, regarding the conflict in Syria, this clause,
under a broad interpretation would give Congress the power to regulate a
potential altercation “that might lead to needless wars or otherwise compromise
the interests” of the nation. But without a broad interpretation, “it is not
entirely clear whence the federal government would derive its needed power to deal
with the noneconomic international incidents” (108) The merit of this broader
interpretation must be considered, especially since the rest of Clause 8 goes
on to discuss matters that are clearly related, especially under this broader
reading, such as “issues of war, armies, navies and militias.” (108) These
topics are not directly related to “commerce” and economic issues, but rather
diplomatic and relations issues. Like many of the documents written by the
Founding Fathers that started at the roots of the country and now serve as
pillars of our government, one must consider the spirit behind what was written
and recognize that it is not always prudent to neither take literally what was
set forth nor confine the words to too specific of an interpretation. With this
in mind, the economic standards that were “sketched out in Jay/Publius’s Federalist No. 2”(108) are prime
examples of the need to take the spirit of the words and apply them to a modern
context.
“Uniform bankruptcy rules would
stabilize interstate lending practices and spur a national market in negotiable
instruments, just as continental standards for copyrights and patents would
create a broad New World market for authors and inventors. Standard weights and
measures, federal post offices and post roads, a continental money supply
alongside uniform regulations of foreign currency—all these would help knit
far-flung Americans together, economically and socially” (108)
With a consideration of the merits
of a free market, the spirit behind the economic standards described in
Federalist No.2 is the presence of some regulation from the government. Is a
free market really “free” if there are regulations? It is perhaps, not. Did
deregulations pull the country into a downward economic spiral, leading to a
recession? Perhaps, yes. The point is not to attempt to “point a finger” at any
one factor that contributed to the current economic failings of the country but
to rather call attention to the spirit with which the men who wrote the
documents that the country was founded upon—and let that influence the way the
words are applied to the law.
No comments:
Post a Comment